

Debunking Some Myths About Competitive Electricity Markets
3.4.05
Jack Ellis

Man’s ability to harness electricity is one of the great technological
and business achievements of the twentieth century. Whole new
industries grew up to build electric production, transmission and
distribution equipment; produce, transport and sell power to end-users;
and invent and build an enormous variety of machines, appliances and
gadgets that would improve our quality of life. Governments eventually
set out an extensive regulatory framework that would ensure the
benefits of electricity were made universally available at reasonable
prices and without some of the competitive excesses that characterized
the industry in its infant years.
By the 1970s however, this once-vibrant industry was under assault.
Regular price decreases turned into price increases as inflation
ravaged the US economy and once robust demand growth suddenly came to a
halt. Air and water pollution became major social issues. Together with
nuclear power safety and cost concerns, these issues undermined the
hard-earned public service image of privately owned utilities.
Customers became frustrated and disenchanted. A once-vibrant industry
that prided itself on customer service became bureaucratic, hidebound
and risk-averse. The flood of technical innovations that kept
electricity prices headed downward for many decades slowed to a
trickle.
Beginning in the late 1970s, elected officials, regulators, thought
leaders, consumer advocates, environmental activists and power industry
representatives initiated a debate over the future structure and
direction of the electric power industry that continues to this day.
Large customers are fed up with what they regard as the excessively
high prices being charged by a monopolistic industry that is neither
efficient nor sensitive to customer needs. Power industry incumbents
see little need for fundamental change and are generally unwilling to
surrender their captive customers. Elected officials and regulators are
struggling to reconcile competing demands for low prices; reliable
service; clean air and water; and a variety of social programs.
Consumer advocates argue passionately for the lowest possible price of
electricity, especially for those living on limited incomes.
The debate is important, and despite the fact that it has been going on
for more than 25 years, many issues remain unresolved. As with any
significant policy debate, participants often get so carried away with
their rhetoric that facts become obscured or even sacrificed during the
struggle to sway public opinion. The discussion that follows is an
attempt to cut through some of the resulting fog and help separate fact
from fiction. It addresses several popular myths and misconceptions
that have evolved around the notion of competitive electricity markets:
“Competition will lead to lower prices”. When proponents of competition make this claim, they run the risk of
undermining their own efforts. Customers, opponents and especially the
press expect to see prices fall literally the day after a competitive
environment is introduced. If price decreases don’t materialize right
away, opponents can rightly make the claim that competition doesn’t
work.
In fact, there’s absolutely no way to know with
certainty how the switch from a regulated monopoly structure to
competition will affect short-run electricity prices, which depend on a
wide range of factors that include the balance between electric supply
and electric demand; prices for coal, natural gas and oil; capital
costs; interest rates; the rate of demand growth; government mandates;
the cumulative effect of customers’ ability to manage demand around
prices; the relative abundance of hydropower; and technological
advances. It becomes a daunting task to draw firm conclusions one way
or the other based on one or two years worth of data when so many
variables can affect the outcome, often in conflicting directions.
Researchers have assembled some evidence to support the claim that
competition does induce incumbent utilities to reduce underlying costs
associated with providing electric service (1). Where it has been
introduced, retail competition has compelled utilities to replace staff
with labor-saving technology, implement work process improvements that
raise productivity, manage parts inventories more effectively, and
replace highly customized parts and systems with less costly
off-the-shelf items. At the wholesale level, merchant generators have
figured out how to dramatically lower the capital and operating costs
of both new and existing generating plants. But fuel prices are still a
significant driver of electricity prices and because fuel prices have
been rising over the last few years, it isn’t clear how all of the
other cost reduction efforts get passed on to customers in the form of
lower retail prices.
Moreover, lower prices aren’t the only motivation for restructuring the
power industry. For some large customers, the ability to negotiate a
better package of terms, conditions and prices may be more important
than just the price of electricity taken alone. But under the current
business and regulatory structure, customers have to negotiate prices
and terms of services in contested regulatory proceedings that are a
matter of public record. In effect, customers must take their suppliers
to court, perhaps many times and in multiple venues simply to negotiate
what for most businesses should just be another supplier agreement. As
an executive at a packing products company once noted, “I buy lots of
commodities on the open market without the help of lobbyists, lawyers
and consultants. I don’t understand why I need them to buy
electricity.”
“Electricity deregulation is a failure everywhere it has been tried…” So says Consumer’s Union in an April 9, 2003 letter on their web site
opposing the Energy Policy Act of 2003. Other signatories to that
letter include the US Public Interest Research Group and the Consumer
Federation of America.
Many of the same kinds of
complaints outlined in Consumer’s Union’s letter were cited by
opponents of the efforts to put airlines and telecommunications
providers on a more competitive footing. Billing errors, poor customer
service, and anti-competitive behavior by the incumbents were rampant.
Several rounds of additional legislation were required to redress
competitive consumer abuses, but there is no longer any doubt that both
industries are in the midst of radical transformations. Air travelers
enjoy an unprecedented range of price and service options, including
air fares that are lower in nominal terms than they were 25 years ago
and air taxi and fractional aircraft ownership options that provide
more convenient point-to-point service and bypass congested air carrier
airports. Telecom users have access to data, voice and video services
that might otherwise have taken many more decades to make the journey
from laboratory research project to commercialization if AT&T’s
monopoly had remained intact. Product and services innovations continue
to come out of these two industries at a rate would never have been
possible under monopoly regulation.
The most negative conclusion one can draw from limited anecdotal
evidence in Consumer’s Union’s letter is that it’s too early to know
whether “deregulation” of the electric power industry is a smashing
success or a dismal failure. Low switching rates, sporadic price
increases, gaming in the UK’s power pool during its early days and the
California debacle are not the kinds of outcomes proponents of
competition were hoping for, but the transformation process is still in
its infancy. On the other hand, the rapid adoption of high efficiency,
low cost, gas-fired combined cycle plants; dramatic increases in
capacity factors and equally dramatic cost reductions at nuclear
plants; and the adoption of price responsive demand management programs
by several RTOs are all the direct result of regulatory initiatives
that were specifically intended to inject a measure of competition in
the power industry.
A corollary to this myth is the argument that “…any potential savings
are outweighed by implementation costs and in any event, cost savings
are too small to be worth the effort.” The potential for competitive
markets to drive down costs and prices is only a part of the benefits
picture. Moreover, even if the savings only amount to a few dollars
each month on a residential electricity bill, those savings are at
least as meaningful as the reduction in banking service charges
consumer advocates often demand or a few pennies of difference in the
price of gasoline.
“Allowing large consumers to shop around will unfairly shift costs to residential and small commercial customers.” This is the response of several influential consumer advocacy
organizations in California to calls for a resumption of retail
competition.
Traditional cost-of-service ratemaking is
much more art than science, and more subjective than objective. The
formulas used to allocate costs among customer classes are heavily
influenced by local politics and the lobbying skills of various
stakeholder groups. They’re not based on fundamental science or
mathematics. As a result, there’s absolutely no objective way to
determine whether the prices paid by any group of customers is “fair”
or to quantify the magnitude of any alleged cross-subsidies. When it
comes to dividing revenue pies, we’re typically more than happy to be
handed an outsized slice. On the cost side, however, we’d just as soon
skip dessert.
Of course, California is a special case prompted by the meltdown of its
wholesale market in 1999 and 2000. There the fairness issue is largely
about how customer groups pay for the expensive long-term power
contracts that were negotiated by political appointees who have since
moved on. TURN, UCAN and the Foundation for Taxpayer and Consumer
Rights, consumer advocacy groups that purport to represent residential
consumers, want the large energy consumers that pushed for
“deregulation” to bear all of the above-market costs associated with
those contracts. Large consumers, merchant energy companies and
competitive retailers oppose exit fees on the grounds that they would
remove any economic incentive to leave bundled utility service.
“Electricity is too important to leave to the free market.” This is simply not true. Food is also an essential commodity subject to
intense competition throughout a supply chain that starts with seed and
fertilizer on one end and puts our dinner on the table at the other. In
the face of such competition, food has become so abundant and so cheap
in this country that many farmers are in the absurd position of being
unable to remain in business without enormous government subsidies.
Limited forms of competition in the electricity sector that are largely
independent of Federal and State restructuring efforts already exist.
One notable example: utilities with adjacent service territories. To
keep large, energy-intensive customers from fleeing, investor-owned
utilities like Public Service Company of Colorado work hard to make
sure their retail rates are not out of line with neighboring public
power agencies. Any retail customer in Lubbock, Texas can take service
from either of two different utilities, Lubbock Power and Light or
Southwestern Public Service (2). As the history of that city’s electric
utility demonstrates, competition can be very effective at keeping
prices in check without compromising service.
By attempting to perpetuate this myth, its proponents imply that the
only options are government ownership or private monopolies. But
governments around the world have embraced private ownership and at
least limited competition rather than public spending as the preferred
means of attracting investment that increase power supply and upgrade
existing facilities.
In conclusion, it is possible the proponents of an industry
restructuring that emphasizes competition will ultimately prove
correct. It is equally possible that none of the many experiments
underway all around the world will yield a new industry model that,
upon critical examination, is deemed better than the old. But while the
debate rages on, it is important that we focus on the facts and not
allow myths to cloud our thinking.
Notes:
1. For example, Kira Markiewicz and Catherine Wolfram of UC Berkeley,
and Nancy Rose of MIT determined that investor-owned utilities in
jurisdictions with competitive electricity markets achieved generating
cost reductions of as much as 10-15% greater than both municipal
utilities and utilities that did not face competitive pressure. See
their joint paper, “Has Restructuring Improved Operating Efficiency at
US Generating Plants?”, UC Energy Institute, July, 2004.
2. http://www.lpandl.com/fullhist.htm
Readers Comments
Date |
Comment |
Thomas Tanton
3.8.05 |
I generally agree with your points, Mr. Ellis. Three additional points
that may need clarification, at least for the public who will
ultimately be asked whether to renew efforts to restructure or
deregulate. First, relative to cost reduction, I think it is important
to point out that cost is only one facet--value of service and
additional services are a fundamental component of other industries
that have deregulated (e.g. in telephony the variety of additional
services such as call-forwarding, call waiting, etc., etc. came about
because of the competition from deregulating) Yes, folks may be paying
a larger phone bill, but only because they are taking more service.
Second, while the crises in California is blamed on deregulation, in
fact it was the result of additional and perpetuated regulation. The
crises stemmed ultimately from a lack of capacity (not energy)
particularly for transmission--which was never touched by
'deregulation'. It is neither true nor fair for critics to state that
deregulation has failed everywhere it's been tried, since in reality it
has never actually been tried ANYWHERE. In every case, domestically and
internationally, there have been changes and elements of a competitive
market, but additional and often even more burdensome regulations
superposed that have acted to stifle competition and new services. This
last factor typically has created self fulfilling prophesies for
failure. |
Len Gould
3.8.05 |
" On the other hand, the rapid adoption of high efficiency, low cost,
gas-fired combined cycle plants; .... are all the direct result of
regulatory initiatives that were specifically intended to inject a
measure of competition in the power industry. "
For that reason alone I consider the (market based) initiatives a
proven failure in the US and elsewhere. Enforcing the lowest common
denominator without provision for any consideration other than next
month's share price, as is the current system, means every citizen has
not only been shafted in price but lost a significant democratic right
and means to ensure considerations other than the short-term bottom
line.
Isn't it fascinating to now hear the litany of "price isn't the only
factor" and "its not really been tried yet" being trotted about? |
George Kamburoff
3.8.05 |
We should fear those for whom price is the only factor of value.
|
Simon Grant
3.8.05 |
Comparing electricity to food.
2 comments
1: food can be stored, frozen etc. Does not have to be consumed immediately it is produced.
2: Wrong analogy: electricity has no substitutes, whereas within the
category of foods are many substitutes: bread for pasta, tea for
coffee. And the existence of substitutes always acts as a sober
prevention against market abuses. |
Dan Potash
3.9.05 |
Jack is right about many things but wrong about why food prices are
low. There has been in the U.S. a massive federally-funded water
development subsidy that lowers food prices.
Also, it is a mistake to claim that IOU's achieved cost reductions from
deregulation more than did municipals. Municipals on average already
had the lower cost of power before deregulation and they still have
lower cost after deregulation.
Last year I debated with an economist friend. He said that electricity
needs time-of-day price signals. I asked if that would help shift
demand by encouraging people to have dinner at midnight, make the kids
do homework at 2 A.M. and do laundry at 4 A.M. He beamed brightly and
said "Yes, exactly!" No wonder California lost $12 billion in
deregulaton. |
Harold Waldock
3.9.05 |
Len Gould suggestion that we lost democratic rights because the
electricity market was deregulated shows that he knows not what
democracy is nor what a market is. Democracy is the rule by the people
but works best where the top state rulers rule little in the lives and
economy of the people because there are many institutions who should
share power and form civil society. Furthermore, it works best were
persons make their own decisions about participation with these
institutions such as markets. If we can not make our own decisions in
an electricity market because either it is operated by a government
sanctioned or de facto monopoly then we are not free to decide who we
do business with. In this way 'open' markets are democratic because
people decide who and how they do business one by one and as groups and
institutions. Tight government control such as a regulated monopoly is
the opposite of open markets and is called socialism which is a variant
of communist ideology. Here in Canada we have BC Hydro, considered one
of the best systems for its low price, high quality service but is much
hated because it is a socialist institution imitating the institutions
of the USSR in a classic form. It offers few choices, is economically
inefficient, causes unemployment, underinvestment and is not responsive
to citizens needs. It also has become a pork barrel operation for
politicians building an expensive gas fired generator in a town where
political debts were to be paid.
Note: An ordered market with civil and government institutions
including an intact justice system can be both lawful, just and
efficient. It is not a laissez faire neoconservative or liberatarian
free for all with no moral or principles taught and enforced. |
|